New on the site: Michi-bot. An intelligent assistant based on the writings of Rabbi Michael Avraham.

Social-Political Polarization: B. A Mathematical View (Column 451)

With God’s help

Disclaimer: This post was translated from Hebrew using AI (ChatGPT 5 Thinking), so there may be inaccuracies or nuances lost. If something seems unclear, please refer to the Hebrew original or contact us for clarification.

Introduction

In the previous column I used an article by Elizabeth Kolbert in The New Yorker to describe the phenomenon of social polarization, where the main issue is not our drift toward extremes but the formation of “mega-identities,” that is, the emergence of correlations between views and traits that shouldn’t be related. In such a situation, a person’s political identity dictates their positions on all the questions on the agenda. We saw there that even taste in television shows differs radically between voters of the two parties in the U.S. They also tend not to date and form romantic ties with one another, and as time goes by their views on every question on the agenda become increasingly aligned with their party identity.

I noted there that two insights arose for me upon reading. The first concerned the knotty situation in which we are dealing with a truly wicked person, which I discussed in the previous column. The second insight concerns a possible mathematical explanation for the phenomenon of polarization. To understand it, I will preface with a review of the K-means algorithm, which I only now learned in a machine-learning course I took (you can watch the relevant lectures here).

A brief preface on machine learning

In machine learning, our goal is to teach the computer a skill or a way to make certain decisions. To illustrate, I’ll use the hackneyed problem of distinguishing between regular email and spam (junk email). If we want to teach the computer to distinguish between these two kinds of email so it can discard the junk, we have two principal ways to do this:

  1. Supervised learning. We give the computer a set of emails that are already labeled as spam or regular email (we ourselves decided which is which), and from this the computer is supposed to learn how to distinguish between the two. After it has trained and learned, from then on the computer should filter the incoming messages. This is supervised learning because we control the data from which the computer learns before it starts operating.
  2. Unsupervised learning. We give the computer an unlabeled set of emails, and it must decide which are spam and which are regular email. Here there is no training phase; the computer proceeds directly to the classification work. This is unsupervised learning because we are not involved in the data itself (we do not control its learning processes).

The second problem sounds like science fiction. How is the computer supposed to understand what junk email is without our teaching it?! Indeed, one could just as well ask how we ourselves do this. At least at the outset, we too have no data and must decide which email is junk to be ignored and which is not. We also learn in an unsupervised way from our experience, and seemingly the computer can do the same. But a computer is not a human being, and as we shall see, even in this case we help it by supplying certain features of junk email that can help it identify it.

In problems of the first kind, the computer is supposed to extract from the labeled examples the relevant parameters that characterize junk email and henceforth use them. Of course, any given email may have many features, some of which are irrelevant to the outcome. The computer is supposed to “understand” which features are relevant from the supervised labeling we present to it. For example, it may notice that every spam email has many recipients, or that each contains purchase offers (prices, sums of money appear), and so on. These are, of course, not decisive features, since they can also appear in regular email, but a weighting of several relevant features can give the computer a very respectable predictive ability (each of us knows from our own inbox how well computers do in this domain—quite well, actually).

But in problems of the second kind the computer lacks supervised guidance. So what can it do? This is what is called a clustering problem: dividing the emails into two groups that are similar within each group, and assuming that one is spam and the other not. For this we must feed the computer relevant features (here it cannot extract them by itself from the labeling, or even choose which of the features matter and which do not. Here we do the work for it). In the junk-email example, we instruct the computer to check, for each email, several parameters: the number of words, how many recipients, how many times a price appears, and so forth, and then to build a table of these features for every email. Suppose we consider four features relevant to distinguishing spam from regular email; then each email has a vector of four features. For example, email #1 has 90 words, 5 prices, 300 recipients, and 10 words that repeat more than twice. We do the same for the second email, the third, and so on. If we have a thousand emails to classify, we create a 4×1000 table where row n contains the four features of email n.

Our goal in unsupervised learning is to divide these thousand emails into two groups according to similarity across the four features so that we can identify the two groups as spam and regular email. For this task one sometimes uses the K-means algorithm.

The K-means algorithm (K-means algorithm)

I’ll preface by noting there is a similarly named algorithm (see about it here) whose goal is to find the locations of K distinct centers to allocate goods to stations scattered in space optimally. The aim is to find a spatial arrangement of centers such that the sum of distances to the stations is minimal. The problem I discuss here is very similar but older (from the 1960s) and concerns clustering in unsupervised machine learning. You can read about it here.

Returning to the email classification mentioned above, we have a clustering problem of dividing the thousand emails into two groups. The K-means algorithm says we should represent each row in this table as a point or a vector in four-dimensional space (whose axes are the four features). In our case, the first email is represented by the point (90, 5, 300, 10), and so forth. Any two locations in this space can be defined as centers (centroids), which we’ll call a and b, and each such pair of centers can define a partition of the emails (points) by their distance to the two. Points closer to center a will be classified into group A, and those closer to b into group B. However, there is no reason to assume that a random choice of positions for the pair of centers will yield a partition that reflects the division between spam and regular email, since this is an arbitrary split. There are infinitely many pairs of centers, and a random choice among them will yield nothing.

To arrive at the “right” partition, or at least close to it, we must see whether there is a partition where the similarity within each of the two groups is “natural” in some sense. We must choose a pair of centers in the four-dimensional space such that the partition they induce on the set of a thousand points is natural. The basic claim here is that the same pair of centers that yields the optimal partition of the thousand points is the one that produces their natural classification, and we identify this with spam versus regular email. What is that optimal partition? We seek a pair of centers such that the sum of distances of the points in the group belonging to each center is optimal, i.e., minimal compared to the sum of distances for any other pair of centers. Why are distances the important similarity parameter? Because we chose the axes (features) to describe the parameters relevant to characterizing spam. If there is proximity along these axes, that means the emails belong to the same group in terms of these parameters, and therefore it is likely that this partition is a good representation of the division between spam and regular emails.

How do we find this optimal pair of centers? For our purposes the key is not the problem and its solution but rather the algorithm I will now define. What we do is arbitrarily choose two points in the space as initial centers, call them a1 and b1. We now divide the thousand points into two groups according to proximity to these two centers. We now have two (not necessarily equal-sized) groups of points, denote them A1 and B1. In the next step we compute the center of each group (their mean position) and define the two points obtained as the next centers: a2 and b2. Now we repeat the process—divide the thousand points anew according to proximity to the new centers—and obtain two new groups (which are indeed expected to differ from the previous ones): A2 and B2. We now compute the mean position of each such group and define the next pair of centers: a3 and b3; then form two new groups of points according to proximity to those centers, A3 and B3; and so on ad nauseam.

In many cases we will get a convergent process, meaning the groups become increasingly optimal (the total distance from the points to their centers decreases). In that case, the process stops at step n, when we obtain the two centers, an and bn, and the two surrounding groups of points, An and Bn, which do not change in the next step. At that point we stop, and these are the optimal centers we sought.

It should be noted that even if the process ends, there is no guarantee we reached the optimal point (it could be a local minimum, i.e., just a fixed point of the transformation), and as far as I understand there is also no guarantee that the process will converge at all at some stage to a minimum (even a local one) and stop.[1] But as a matter of fact, in many cases it does work, and it turns out that in quite a few cases this is a reasonable way to predict the two desired clusters.

Interim summary

I described the process for the case of a split into two centers (K=2). Of course, such processes can be performed for any number of centers we define. For example, we can take height and weight data of T-shirt consumers and represent each customer as a point in a two-dimensional plane. We can then divide the points into three optimal groups to decide which sizes will define the three types of shirts we produce (small, medium, large). This is an application of the algorithm with K=3. In the email example I focused on the case K=2 because, for our purposes later, that will be the relevant example.

I recommend seeing here some simulations of this process in two-dimensional space (I suggest choosing two clusters for simplicity).[2] You can also watch a YouTube video that presents the topic simply and nicely for higher dimensions. If you follow these simulations, you will see the gradual process of forming the two centers. You’ll see that at each stage the centers move through space until their final positions, and of course at each stage the surrounding groups change and reorganize accordingly. It is important to remember that each such center point defines, at every stage, an approximation to the typical feature set of spam (the a-series) or regular email (the b-series). As the process advances, the combination of features at the center changes gradually, and of course so do the groups of points (emails) around it, defined by their similarity to it. Thus a1 is an arbitrary combination of features, but the next combination, a2, is already the beginning of forming the typical combination. The final combination, an, is our final prediction for the typical combination of spam features. The combination bn represents, of course, the typical combination of features of regular email. Around them are clustered the points similar to each (i.e., close to them in feature values), and this is the outcome of the process for the two corresponding groups of emails.

We can now move on to a proposed explanation for the political polarization processes described above.

Back to political polarization

As we saw in the previous column, the explanations offered for polarization processes usually invoke psychological planes, namely the movement of public opinion over time toward polarized directions. Various mechanisms and explanations were offered there (such as the impact of social networks), and I’m sure there are others. But in light of what we have seen thus far, I thought we could offer a mathematical explanation unrelated to psychology. To highlight its different nature, I will assume for the sake of discussion (an implausible assumption) that voters do not change their minds at all over the course of the process. We will see that nevertheless, along the way the groups organize themselves in such a way that polarization necessarily emerges. If I can convince you that this is indeed what happens, then this process is not psychological but mathematical-political.

Consider a democratic process of repeated elections every few years between two parties, as in the U.S. Suppose our voters are represented by a set of views (=features), and each voter is represented by a point in a high-dimensional space (whose axes are the features of political views: position between capitalism and socialism, hawkishness on security, attitude toward the judiciary, religion and state, and so forth). In the U.S. there are two dominant parties, each trying to recruit as many voters as possible. My assumption for this discussion is that each voter chooses the party whose platform is closest to them (not only do the inhabitants of our Utopia not change their views, they also act according to reason and values. They have no gut and no emotions. In fact, this island is not called “Utopia” but “Asperger Island”). You can see that we’ve created a two-center problem here (each representing the views offered by the Democratic or Republican parties, denoted a and b) that partitions the voters into two parties. Let us now look at the democratic process and see that it fully parallels the process of forming centers as described above.

At the first stage two parties arise with some platform. For our discussion we will assume this is an arbitrary beginning, i.e., it does not necessarily relate to the voters’ views (since they have not yet been tested at the polls). The two views/platforms are represented by two centers located at points a1 and b1 in the high-dimensional space. Each such platform recruits to its side the voters whose views are closest to it, and accordingly wins their votes in the first elections to be held there (after the American War of Independence, in the late 18th century). Now the two centers have formed around them two groups of voters, A1 and B1 respectively. But if you now check the mean location of each of the two groups, you will discover that it is not at a1 and b1 but elsewhere. We compute them and denote them a2 and b2. In such a situation, ahead of the second elections, it is clear that the views a1 and b1 are not optimal for the two parties, since they do not necessarily fit the views of most voters.

What happens now? In principle, a new party could arise, of course, but in the American system the mechanism is that a new candidate arises within each of the two parties who detects the potential and positions themselves (their platform) at the new locations that have emerged. At this stage there are primaries among the party’s voters, namely among the members of groups A1 and B1. Note that those participating are the members of the groups from the previous partition still.[3] They will of course choose the second candidate rather than the first (unless the first changed their positions as is customary in our regions, and then the first themselves will be the second), since the second is at a more optimal location for them. After the primaries there are elections, and the new candidate tries to recruit additional votes from the entire electorate.

What happens now? The voters, of course, choose between the two new candidates, and therefore the election results repartition all voters into two new groups, A2 and B2 respectively. These are the groups appropriate to the new centers a2 and b2. But now again there is a gap that requires a new positioning of the centers. New candidates choose platforms a3 and b3 and are elected in the primaries. In the general elections to be held for the new candidates, groups A3 and B3 will form. The process, of course, repeats itself over and over; at each stage the centers shift and the groups cluster around them in a slightly different way. All this continues until Bibi arrives. He is the fixed point of the process and remains forever (until a legal-political assassination of a sitting prime minister occurs).[4]

Note that at each stage of this process, greater internal cohesion emerges among views that more naturally fits the natural division of voters into two groups. The center (i.e., the party platform) shifts slightly each time until it reaches a state that gathers the citizens around it in a “natural” and optimal way. The process should end when optimal candidates emerge who manage to capture the votes of most voters, i.e., whose views fit most of their potential voters. This is the stable state and, in principle, it should not change. Needless to say, it never really stops because the picture is more complex. New axes and new challenges are constantly being added that require a position to be formed about them as well, and the space changes. But this mechanism is sufficient for me to provide a model that describes one of the vectors in the political process of polarization.

If at each stage of this process coherence increases within each of the two groups and they fit more optimally to their “natural” center, then we have precisely the process described above as a “mega-identity,” namely, correlation across different axes. Suddenly party membership, Democratic or Republican, radiates onto views across all spheres of life (across all the axes and features of socio-political agendas). In voter group An, which is close to the ideological pole an, there are now people who like the same movies, form romantic ties with the same people (and not with members of the other party), and think similarly about abortion, the economy, security, the judiciary, religion and state, and much more. As this process advances, the positions of all party members on all axes become more synchronized with one another (it is, of course, far from merging, but the correlation intensifies).

A bird’s-eye view of the process and its implications

Note that all this happens even if no voter has changed their position. The re-drawing of the front lines of party platforms and the voters themselves into two groups creates this polarization. This is how the two “mega-identities” described above arise. The front lines organize themselves to achieve maximal polarization, not in the sense of extreme and very different views, but in the sense of correlations across different fields of opinion (correlation across axes). That is, this is a process that is not psychological but mathematical-political. It is not based on dynamics in voters’ views but on dynamics in the partition of the given voters (even if they hold frozen views) into two groups.

Note that as a result of this mechanism, the two polarized views do not necessarily move farther apart (i.e., become more extreme). In fact, the exact opposite is expected. Since each party strives to maximize votes, it strives to be as close as possible to the majority of voters (the majority of points in the space). It is no wonder, then, that the positions of the centers (=party platforms) move closer to one another.[5] The two parties strive to position themselves at the mean position of all voters (not only of those who traditionally vote for them), meaning they circle around the very same place. This is a possible explanation for the familiar paradox: the closer the positions are, the more the attitudes polarize and the hostility grows. An inverse relation arises between the distances in views and the intensity of hostility and polarization between the groups of voters who hold them. The smaller the distance between them, d(an, bn), the greater the hostility between the groups An and Bn.

If you look at today’s political map in Israel, you will find it difficult to point to ideological differences between Likud and Labor, New Hope, Yesh Atid, Blue and White, Lieberman, Yamina, and the like. Almost all parties and Knesset members crowd together at an almost uniform center, and the differences between them are truly minor, if they exist at all. No one can point to the differences between them, simply because there are almost none. It is no wonder that Knesset members move freely between parties according to the advancement and electability offered to them. They don’t even need to change positions or platform to do so. It is common to blame such MKs for lacking ideology, but that is not correct. They do not need to change ideology to move to another party, since there is no ideological difference between the parties. And at the same time, as perceptual and ideological gaps narrow, the hostility between the sides reaches unprecedented heights. The enmity focuses on trifles belonging to the margins of the disputes, and these are magnified as if they were momentous disagreements. Each side sees the other as malicious, and in the absence of an ideological difference, the conflict and enmity focus mainly on the personal plane (pro- or anti-Bibi/Trump).

Incidentally, what is currently called, sometimes derisively, the “change government,” is a historic event from this vantage point. They essentially tried to break the dichotomous division into “mega-identities,” and to connect parties with different platforms (with the common denominator being that they do not want bn, or bb, of course). No wonder the dinosaurs built by polarization on both sides accuse them of leftism on the one hand, or capitulation to the right on the other. These accusations try to forcibly preserve the “mega-identity” and the polarization arising from it. This is similar to clinging to the horns of the altar of polarization between religious “mega-identities”: religious-Zionist and Haredi, which also no longer really exists. Its preservation is in the interest of those who feed off this polarization (and of course they always speak of “unity of the camp”). Instead of dividing along real poles—Haredi (Zionist or not) versus liberal—people prefer to divide along the axis of Zionism versus anti-Zionism, which today has no real content.

Returning to the process of political polarization, note that this entire process can and is expected to occur even if throughout it no one changes their position on any issue. The “mega-identity” arises due to the organization of voters into “natural” groups with higher internal coherence. This is an outcome of the democratic process itself. Therefore polarization, in this sense (not in the sense of extremism—since extremism actually disappears—but in the sense of the emergence of correlations—the “mega-identity”), is not despite democracy but because of it. Elections and the replacement of candidates (internal elections, primaries) create an organization and consolidation of centers in a way that maximizes polarization (creates a “mega-identity”), just like in the K-means algorithm.

The relationship between the two explanations

I do not intend to claim that the psychological explanations are incorrect. On the contrary, it is quite clear to me that they are correct. But to the same extent, the mechanistic-political-mathematical explanation is also correct. The conclusion is that the process of political polarization is a combination of these two mechanisms together. Polarization is created by the radicalization of views due to echoing within social-network bubbles, and at the same time by a process of center-organization that would occur even if there were no change at all in voters’ views.

The first insight seemed quite discouraging. If everyone is sure they are right and the other is wicked, there is no chance they will be willing to examine themselves and give the other credit. That is a psychological knot. The second insight seems, at first glance, even more discouraging, since ostensibly it is an almost deterministic process. We saw that it is inherent in the democratic structure and our form of government. It is no wonder that the author quotes Stephen Marche (a Canadian writer and journalist cited in the previous column) saying:

“No American president of any party, now or in the foreseeable future, can be a symbol of unity, only of division.” Unfortunately, too many of his declarations sound correct, like “When the crisis comes, the institutions will not be there.”

This is also the feeling regarding our situation here in Israel.

And yet, I thought that at the end of the tunnel of the second mechanism there may be light, since here we are not dealing with a psychological blockage but with a result of a structural-governmental mechanism. Therefore, precisely here I have some hope for improvement and repair, if we can think of a way to change the mechanism of center-organization and the groups around them. I will propose two lines of thought derived from the picture I have described, and due to the shortness of the platform I hope you will forgive the preliminary and non-concrete nature of what follows.

Two principal directions for change

The first direction is to periodically change axes, or add axes to the ideological map. How is this done? For example, by adopting new challenges and placing them before the public. Once there are additional issues that require attention, opinions divide differently, and the process of forming “mega-identities” can be temporarily broken (but of course begin again and strive to reconverge around new centers).

The author of the article also notes that finding a shared task that unites both sides can change the situation. This claim, too, is supported by experiments in social psychology. Incidentally, the Kodkod Games company has a whole series of non-zero-sum games, i.e., games whose success is based on cooperation rather than confrontation and competition (in game theory we distinguish between these two types). We all know the phenomenon that in situations of internal conflict and tension the ruler and/or the public find a common enemy on whom to vent their anger and thus try to achieve internal unity (some will say sweep the problem under the rug, but here we see there is something substantive to it). This is an application of this method, albeit at the expense of an external party. Finding a task that requires internal cooperation without directing it against an external enemy could be more successful and positive, but of course much harder.

The second direction is to think about changing the electoral system. We should seek a mechanism that neutralizes center-organization in a way that maximizes polarization. For example, perhaps we can define, each time, a certain set of questions on which the current elections are held. Perhaps we can add and remove centers, i.e., artificially change the number of parties (changing the electoral threshold is such a process). Although nowadays we have many parties, there are still two fairly distinct sides on our political map (at least until Bennett, Sa’ar, and Lieberman—those wicked traitors—broke the underlying “mega-identities”). Therefore, at least de facto, our political mechanism is the organization of two centers. One could also think about a system where the citizen votes for whom they do not want, or where each person ranks all the parties, and so on.

Can these directions for change be brought about by the politicians who themselves create these processes? Is this not a solution of the sort we saw above (“behave logically and nicely and then everything will be solved”)? At least in some situations, the answer may be negative. They will do so only if it suits their political interest. For example, Israel today suffers from political deadlock (though after the Netanyahu era, no one will remember that anyone here thought about a deadlock. The deadlock is not between right and left but between Bibi and anti-Bibi). In a political tie, perhaps even the politicians will conclude that the existing polarization does not necessarily serve their interest. Changing and reorganizing centers will not necessarily reduce your number of voters (=the points close to you). If you manage to define additional axes that bring most voters closer to your center, or position your center to be closer to more voters, you can gain politically from this process. And then, of course, it will begin anew, and so on and so forth…

[1] As far as I know, if similarity is defined via Euclidean distance between a point and its relevant center, I believe it does converge.

[2] You’ll see that if there are two centers (K=2), the separation between them is by a straight line (and in three dimensions or more we get a plane or a higher-dimensional hyperplane). If there are more centers we get polygonal shapes around each center. There are also techniques to create separations that are not straight (not polygons), like circles or any other shape, but I won’t get into that here.

[3] In the U.S., the primaries of each party are held among the general electorate and not only party members. I assume participation is indeed divided (voters of each party want to influence their party’s candidates), but for our purposes here it doesn’t matter. I’m merely presenting a model to explain the polarization process.

[4] Either because he changes his positions to match the electorate (as the saying goes: “These are my principles, but if you’d like I have others as well”), or because the voters emigrated from Asperger Island and moved to Utopia. Specifically regarding Bibi, I think he does more or less maintain his positions (because he is always elected regardless of his views and therefore does not need to change them to be elected). He may not act based on his views, but that’s another discussion. I am speaking about what the candidate says, not what he does.

[5] Incidentally, this does not happen in the algorithm itself. The tendency to approach all the points in the space characterizes the political game but not the algorithm. The algorithm only seeks an optimal partition and has no interest in maximizing the number of points in each group. If we add that constraint to the algorithm, we get the political game more fully. In that case the two centers will, of course, position themselves at the centroid of all the points.

16 תגובות

  1. Your argument is that there is always a force toward division, because in every group there is a division into two (or more) very different subgroups, and therefore the struggle will persist and only decrease in resolutions. But there is also a force toward unification, because unification allows for an increase in power. Nadav Shnarb once wrote on Facebook that on the contrary, the representatives of the two groups will try to be as close as possible - the right-wing representative has an interest in going left to the point closest to the right of the left-wing representative, because in this way he maximizes the number of points that are closer to him than to the left-wing representative. Another and more important thing is that perhaps an ideological difference that is in small resolutions will no longer be enough to sustain stable polarization, because people can understand that it is not critical. In a capitalist world of individual people, it is assumed that everyone has their own special interest: to take care of themselves, and there is no polarization as polarized, and yet people voluntarily unite for the benefit of all and no one partner has a narrow eye on the pocket of another partner to take that from him as well. So what is the problem with subgroups splitting up and voluntarily uniting.

    1. See note 5 and surroundings. I wrote this. But it is not a unification but a rapprochement of the centers.
      And beyond that, my goal here was to give a model that would illustrate a polarization mechanism that is not related to psychology. It is clear that in practice there are many more factors that need to be introduced (from Asperger to utopia, for example).

      1. And at the edge of the polarizations stand individual people, as you wrote in response to the previous column, and then voluntary unions will begin, which over time and as they grow (from additional unions or from culture) will split into several. And what's wrong with that? Some will say that all of this has already happened and is happening. It's just a shame that the flexibility of alliances between groups is not higher, as this would supposedly maximize the global consensus, like any free market.

        1. My problem is not the division, nor the extremism. My problem is an irrelevant approach through imaginary correlations that leads to, and perhaps is also led by, unjustified hostility.

  2. In the words of S. T. Bader, P. B.

    The mathematical algorithm of the concentration of many different points around centers despite the lack of identity in all details - nicely explains the phenomenon of parties, in which groups that are similar to each other unite around one ‘center’ relatively close to everyone. Sometimes the ’stick’ is a shared ideology, sometimes the appreciation of a charismatic leader, and sometimes it is hatred or aversion against an unpopular phenomenon or group. However, the hostility and bitter rivalry between the groups is not necessary.

    I think that hostility is brought about by another mathematical algorithm, and it is the principle of ’majority’. When a dominant group loses its ’majority’it becomes ’opposition’ – The hegemons who have fallen from the position of rulers develop hostility towards the ’slave that he may reign’. All the more so is added to the hostility of the deposed hegemons as the ’timeline’ in which they are down grows longer. And the feeling of hostility increases when the deposed hegemons have a ‘multidimensional’self-image; and see themselves as a surplus of educated and enlightened scientists, who are now being oppressed by ignorant and dark ones. Who compensate for the loss of the quantitative majority with a ’qualitative majority’

    The appropriate solution to the problem of ‘loss of the majority’ is to increase the birth rate. When the liberal and progressive leftists establish families with many children – their numerical strength will increase and their control will be restored. After all, people of high socioeconomic status can afford to support many more children. And as the people of ‘natural selection’ would have it: ‘Children are joy, children are a blessing. Have lots of children!’

    Best regards, Simcha Fish”l Plankton Halevi

    1. In the S”D Y’ Bader”r P”B

      Contrary to the opinion of the post writer, the ideological differences between the parties are quite clear. ‘Yesh Atid’ and ’Blue and White’ take the position in the political sphere of the ‘historical Labor Party’ from the Rabin-Peres era, which supported the ’peace process’ whose goal is to establish ‘two states for two peoples’. While the Likud (of which ’New Hope’ is a faction) advocate opposition to a fake ’peace process’in which the Palestinians are implicated in supporting terrorism and striving to destroy the State of Israel. They cannot completely deny the ’Oslo Accords’ to which the State of Israel is committed – but they ‘impale’ them de facto in their aggressive demand that the Palestinians renounce terrorism as a necessary condition for any political progress.

      ‘Yamina’ took a more aggressive path than Likud on the political level and strongly demanded the application of sovereignty to all of Judea and Samaria and completely rejected any willingness for a Palestinian state. By joining the ’Hissavi government’, ‘Yamina’ and ’New Hope’ gave their leftist partners control over the political-security centers of power. The left received the foreign, defense, and internal security portfolios. Bennett also appointed Shimrit Meir, who in an interview with her made it clear that she is a Blue and White supporter, as his political advisor. The people of Yamina are still trying to appear "right-wing", but it is clear that they are unable to fundamentally change the political orientation of their partners on the left.

      On the "religion and state" axis, there is a division that does not overlap with the "political-security" axis. Bennett, who is at least outwardly "ultra-right" from a political-security perspective, is, after all, on matters of "religion and state" his "brothers in the Brotherhood" partner – Lapid and Lieberman – who aspire to abolish the state status of Orthodoxy in Israel, by abolishing the halachic authority of the Chief Rabbinate and giving the liberal rabbinate the opportunity to create a liberal ‘kashrut’ that would also grant kosher status to restaurants open on Shabbat and factories that do not strictly inspect for insects, etc., and would provide for mass conversion without receiving mitzvot. Kashrut and conversion in the style of Lieberman and Julia Malinowski – are also acceptable to Bennett and Saar.

      In short: the tone-setters in this government both in the political-security field and in the fields of ‘religion and state’ are Lapid Gantz and Lieberman. We are fortunate that there is still a party with a religious orientation left to run for office – It is a shame that its Shura Council constitutes a certain brake on the progressive race. Congratulations 🙂

      With best wishes, Yaron Fishel Ordner

  3. Raanana's angle is thought-provoking. It seems to me that one process that the system has gone through over the years is parallel to finding PCA (Principle Component Analysis) in which a multidimensional space is mapped to a smaller dimension. In our case, the mapping is to a one-dimensional world known as left-right. As the years go by, the system goes through iterations that make the mapping better (in the sense of the best separation between the groups. Now we actually have a one-dimensional problem. Let's assume that positive X is right and negative is left as is customary. And let's assume a homogeneous distribution of the points between -1 and 1. The K-MEAN algorithm would find centers at plus and minus half. But in fact, any symmetrical solution is equivalent. And so is plus/minus epsilon (in a practical sense) and plus/minus infinity (in a conscious sense).

  4. I really liked the idea!
    Just a note regarding the mention of raising the electoral threshold as a situation/solution that will reduce polarization:
    When clustering is done using k means and so on, the question always arises of how many clusters (or parties in the example) will give the best solution. You can create a graph whose y-axis is the total distances from the points and the x-axis is the number of points that serve as centers. Usually, the difference between 2 and 3 centers in terms of the number of distances will be greater than the difference between 12 and 13. A good choice of the number of clusters instead of a graph where the difference between the points becomes relatively small. (Choosing too many points is also not good of course)

    Under the reasonable assumption that there are fewer people at the ideological extremes and opinions are divided like a bell curve, using the k-means algorithm with 2 centers will cause the 2 centers to be distant because of the extreme points
    In such a situation, if we choose 4 centers, the two centers that capture the most people will be much closer
    Therefore, in a political system that traditionally works with 2 parties or a system that is heading in this direction with only Bibi or RLB, the distance between the centers will be large compared to a situation where the number of parties corresponds to the distribution of opinions in the population more naturally.
    In the parable, it looks like this - because today there is only Gush Bibi and not Bibi - suddenly Bibi becomes more “Haredi” and will not implement parts of his liberal concept that is closer to Lapid, let's say. This is because the center that Bibi represents needs to capture the points of the Haredim (even if in practice they don't vote for him)

  5. In simpler terms. A system with 2 parties or blocs is affected by ideological extremes much more than a system with 4.
    The radicalization of the left-wing Democrats affects the “center point” of half of the population of the United States.
    All of this, of course, explains the polarization in the context of radicalization (that the Democrats have become more progressive, etc.) and less the matter of imaginary correlations.

    1. In the Sed, he carried a load on both shoulders.

      To Avishai, greetings

      We have already been taught by the great Rabbi of Netzach Israel and Newton in his laws of physics, that when a powerful force is exerted in one direction, an opposing force acts in the opposite direction.

      Therefore, when there is excessive extremism to one side, a reactionary reaction is created to the other. And so the rise of the crazy progressive left in America is what gave rise to Trump, who dared to speak out against the left-wing and liberal conventions. Of course, the American left has escalated its fight against Trump to violent riots by blacks, relentless legal and media persecution, and mass election fraud. And extremism leads to extremism in the outbreak of Trump supporters at the Capitol.

      What stops the snowball of mutual polarization is: that most people like to live peacefully and prefer to follow the ‘middle path’ that does not break the ‘rules of the game’, and therefore Trump's deputy and his family refused to cooperate and also influenced him to ‘accept justice’ despite being ‘a cheated justice’ and wait for the next opportunity’. On the other hand, there were enough senators who prevented a decision in the opposite direction and refused to disqualify Trump, and thus the ‘middle ground’ was maintained.

      This is also what happened with us when the MDA insisted on removing the father and mother’ from their patients, and on the other hand, the other side decided to boycott blood donations even though the father could be life-threatening. And in the end, a compromise was reached: the MDA removed both the ‘father and mother’ and the ‘parent 1 and parent 2′ and most of the religious Zionist yeshiva returned to donating blood.

      As Hegel said: thesis and antithesis – Bringing to Synthesis 🙂

      With blessings, Yosef Zvi Bidani Levi-Trumpetist

      And before Haggai, the prophet Elijah is remembered for good, (in the opening of Elijah in the Book of Zohar) who taught us that the ways of divine leadership follow the path of ‘one long, one short, and one medium’

      1. The parallel in the idea of the "force that drives opposing forces" between Mahar”el and Newton could also stem from a real connection, since Newton was a student of Kepler, a student of Tycho Brahe, who was a friend of Mahar”el, but it is possible that the idea was already common in the scientific literature of the Renaissance. I don…t know…

        Best regards, Yakov Levit

  6. Regarding the first direction, I believe that the parties in Israel should have placed the issue of the family on their banner. It started with the fact that the housing problem in Israel could change if there were fewer divorces, and of course many other economic considerations that affect this (credit points for single parents and so on). Of course, the value of family life and everything that entails it could also be a topic that is discussed and studied in the education system (which is what is in the Halmish government but in broad aspects that are suitable for all sectors). There is such a minister in Scandinavia - the Minister of Family Affairs.
    But even if this axis is established, it will return to the issue of Avi Maoz, the man who took the line against Horowitz, the LGBTQ+

  7. I haven't read the comments, so I don't know if this has already been said, but your first suggestion seems to me to be exactly what happened with the LGBT struggle, which until two decades ago was frowned upon and reviled even in the most permissive secular society, and today it is already an issue that polarizes religious society.

  8. This autism always makes me laugh again. After all, the problem he points out is that people are controlled by their egos. Whether it's politicians who don't believe in anything except that they need to rule, or whether it's voters who think it's a football game and there are teams (how does the left have voters? What's wrong with these people? What kind of mental illness is this? Maybe brain damage?) Then he tries to solve the essential problem with a formal solution. Let's add more axes of polarization. Let's create more football teams... right. That's what will solve this problem. Instead of polarization of two teams, there will be polarization of four teams, eight teams, and sixteen teams...

    This itself is the logic of leftists...

  9. Woe to us, for we have heard that you have left the source of living water to hew out broken cisterns.
    How did you leave physics and go to the mill?!?

  10. They will heal a major fracture easily. (With an appropriate algorithm)
    In the 2016 elections, Hillary Clinton called Republican voters a basket of deplorables
    I checked the THESAURUS.COM website for synonyms for deplorables:
    disgraceful, distressing, awful, horrifying, and more in that vein.
    And with us: mezuzah kissers, primitive, herd, and the most gentle expression messianic.
    No mathematical algorithm will help with this disease.

Leave a Reply

Back to top button